- 35 - b. The Strong Proof Rule Alternatively, respondent contends that the strong proof rule applies here. Ullman v. Commissioner, 264 F.2d 305, 308 (2d Cir. 1959); Meredith Corp. & Subs. v. Commissioner, 102 T.C. 406, 438 (1994); Elrod v. Commissioner, supra at 1066; Coleman v. Commissioner, supra at 202 & n.17; G C Servs. Corp. v. Commissioner, 73 T.C. 406, 412 (1979). In Ullman, the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit held that a taxpayer-buyer had to produce strong proof to overcome allocations of value in an agreement it negotiated with a seller which had an adverse tax position. In Ullman, the Court of Appeals said that tax adversity forces most buyers and sellers to use realistic values when they allocate the purchase price in an agreement. Ullman v. Commissioner, supra at 308; see Schulz v. Commissioner, 294 F.2d at 55 ("Generally speaking, the countervailing tax considerations upon each taxpayer should tend to limit schemes or forms which have no basis in economic fact."); UMCO Corp. v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1973-218 (conflicting tax interests are a prerequisite to applying the strong proof rule). The rationale for the strong proof rule does not apply here because the seller did not care about and the parties did not negotiate the allocations; Schulz v. Commissioner, supra, Ullman v. Commissioner, supra. Respondent has given no reason for it to apply beyond thePage: Previous 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 Next
Last modified: May 25, 2011