- 61 - income into 1984. Petitioners' actual trading patterns may indeed have become more idiosyncratic, but the trades still represented substantial tax avoidance. Another indication of a lack of economic substance is the fact that the prices of the items traded on the Merit markets were not set by market forces. Instead, the prices were set by Merit itself, according to formulas derived by its employees. As was the case in Freytag v. Commissioner, supra, the parties have expended a great deal of time, energy, and resources in arguing the theoretical viability of Merit's pricing structure for options and forwards. Those considerations are largely irrelevant. The loss legs of tax straddles presented the opportunity for large tax losses at the end of a taxable year. Economically, these are not losses at all, because they are balanced by the offsetting (but unrealized for tax purposes) gain legs. Thus, alleged negotiations between Merit and its customers as to the prices of the legs are not particularly significant, because the prices offset each other. We explained that point in Smith v. Commissioner, 78 T.C. 350, 379 (1982): Neither were petitioners' prices the product of an economically adversarial or tax-consequence adversarial process. While the relative prices of straddle legs are of great economic consequence to a straddle trader, the absolute prices have little or no economic significance. The buyer or seller of a straddle suffers no economic benefit or detriment by agreeing to leg prices above the market or below the market. To the extent that one leg is economically deprived of its true value by such pricing, the other leg's value is equally enhanced. * * * [Fn. ref. omitted.24] 24 Moreover, the historic stock prices, rates, and (continued...)Page: Previous 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 Next
Last modified: May 25, 2011