- 19 - lawsuit to Norway, and then Norway transferred the lawsuit to petitioners for their BFI stock. This might result in tax consequences to both BFI, see sec. 311(b), and Norway either at the time of the distribution or at the time of the settlement. In Henry Schwartz Corp. v. Commissioner, 60 T.C. 728, 738- 739 (1973), we recognized the interplay of the tax effects of particular transactions and their intended structure, stating: In this regard it is important to note that the parties to the agreement, Henry and Sydell and Suval, were dealing at arm’s length and indeed had conflicting interests with respect to the treatment of the policy. Thus, if the distribution of the policy was considered as part of the overall price for the stock, and the distribution was from Plastic Calendering to Suval and then to Henry, then Suval might be charged with a dividend on the initial distribution of the policy to it. See Frithiof T. Christensen, 33 T.C. 500, 504-505. On the other hand, if the policy were distributed to Henry by Plastic Calendering, not as part of the purchase price for the stock but simply because the purchaser did not want this asset and the sellers had agreed that it would not be part of the sale, then Henry might be charged with receipt of a dividend. See John R. West, 37 T.C. 684, 687. Thus, the agreement between the parties represents an accurate reflection of an arm’s-length transaction, and this agreement makes it clear that the policy was distributed from Plastic Calendering to Suval and then to Henry. Surely, if petitioners’ characterization of the transactions in this case were correct, a reduced purchase price would have been negotiated reflecting BFI’s or Norway’s tax liability for those amounts. Instead, the purchase price continued to reflect the book value of the assets and liabilities of BFI. It appears from the record that the parties to the stock sale were relativelyPage: Previous 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Next
Last modified: May 25, 2011