- 54 - B nonvoting stock. In addressing the economic theory underlying voting rights valuation, Dr. Spiro opined that because decedent's class A voting stock constitutes only a 23.55-percent voting interest in J.R. Simplot Co., it does not enable the hypothetical buyer to exercise all the prerogatives of control. However, relying on empirical evidence, Dr. Spiro noted that nonmajority voting blocks of sufficient size are valued at a premium in the marketplace in excess of the pro rata equity value represented by those blocks. Moreover, analyzing the available studies, Dr. Spiro suggested that voting premiums, if measured on a per-share basis against nonvoting or low-voting shares (a "simple voting premium"), are affected by the scale factor--generally, a small proportion of voting stock in a capital structure tends to produce a high per- share voting premium, pointing to the utility of calculating the value of the aggregate voting stock as a percentage of total equity capitalization (the "aggregate voting rights percentage"). Dr. Spiro also analyzed U.S. public markets, noting their limitations and impediments to the trading of nonvoting stock. In his view, it is unlikely that a company with a similar capital structure to J.R. Simplot Co.'s would list its securities on the U.S. exchanges. Moreover, he believed that a simple voting stock price premium24 is irrelevant to the valuation of the class A voting shares because the U.S. dual-capitalization stock price data for 24 Dr. Spiro defines a simple voting stock price premium as the percentage difference between voting share prices and nonvoting or inferior-voting share prices.Page: Previous 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 Next
Last modified: May 25, 2011